Corporate Governance In India Evolution And Challenges Finance Essay

Published: November 26, 2015 Words: 4991

The theme of corporate governance leapt to universal business attention from relative anonymity after a sequence of collapses of high profile companies. Enron, the Houston, Texas bound energy giant, and WorldCom, the telecom behemoth, surprised the business community with the kind of mammoth scam and the tenure of their disreputable and illegitimate operations. Despite all that it is believed that, they seemed to indicate only the tip of a dangerous iceberg. At the same time as corporate practices in the US companies came under attack, it appeared so as to the problem was far more prevalent. Outsized and trusted companies from Parmalat in Italy to the multinational newspaper group Hollinger Inc., exposed noteworthy and innate problems in their corporate governance. Still the prestigious New York Stock Exchange has to remove its boss, Dick Grasso, amidst civic outcry over disproportionate compensation. It was clear so as to incredible was amiss in the area of corporate governance all over the world.

Corporate governance has, of course, been an imperative field of inquiry within the finance discipline for ages. Researchers in finance encompass actively investigated the topic for at least a quarter century (Jensen and Meckling (1976) and the father of modern economics, Adam Smith, himself had acknowledged the problem over two centuries ago. There have been debates concerning whether the Anglo-Saxon market- model of corporate governance is superior to the bank-based models of Germany and Japan. However, the difference in the quality of business governance in these developed countries fade in assessment to the abyss that exist amid corporate governance standards and practices in these countries as a group and those in the rising economy. Shleifer and Vishny (1997)

Corporate governance turned to be a central issue with developing countries much before the topical wave of corporate indignity in superior economies became headlines. Certainly corporate governance and financial development are essentially linked. Successful corporate governance systems endorse the development of sturdy financial systems - with out any coherence of whether they are principally bank-based or market-based - which, in turn, have a distinctly affirmative effect on financial growth and poverty reduction. Claessens (2003)

At present are a number of channels all the way through which the causality works. Effectual corporate governance enhances admittance to peripheral financing by firms, foremost to better investment, as sound as privileged growth and employment. The ratio of private credit to GDP of countries in the peak quartile of creditor right performance and enforcement is more than twofold that in the countries in the lowest quartile. La Porta et al (1997)

Pertaining to equity financing, the proportion of stock market capitalization to GDP in the countries during the highest quartile of investor right enactment and enforcement is a propos four times as big as that for countries in the lowest quartile. Deprived corporate governance also becomes the hurdle for the creation and development of new firms.

Excellent corporate governance also reduces the cost of capital by mitigating risk and creates high firm valuation once again promoting real investments. La Porta et al (2000)

There is a difference of a factor of 8 in the "control premium" (transaction price of shares in wedge transfers suggesting control transfer less the ordinary share price) amid countries with the highest level of equity rights safety and those with the lowest. Dyck and Zingales (2000)

Effective corporate governance system make certain about better resource allocation and management raising the return to capital. The return on assets (ROA) is about twice as high in the countries with the highest level of equity rights protection as in countries with

the lowest protection. Claessens (2003)

Good corporate governance can significantly reduce the risk of nation-wide financial crises. There is a strong inverse relationship between the quality of corporate governance and currency depreciation. Johnson et al (2000)

Certainly meager transparency and corporate governance norms are supposed to be the key reasons following the Asian Crisis of 1997. Such economic crises have immense social and economic and can set a country some years back in its path to development.

Finally, better corporate governance can remove distrust amid diverse stakeholders, reduce legal costs and develop labor and social relationships and peripheral economies like environmental protection.

Making certain that the middle management in fact act on behalf of the owners of the company - the stockholders - and go by on the profits to them are the solution issues in corporate governance. Incomplete liability and discrete ownership - necessary features that the joint-stock company outline of organization thrives on - unavoidably lead to a distance and incompetent monitoring of management by the genuine owners of the business. Managers have the benefit of actual control of business and may perhaps not serve in the best interests of the shareholders. These probable problems of corporate governance are worldwide. In addition, the Indian economic sector is discernible with a relatively unsophisticated equity market defenseless to manipulation and with elementary analyst movement; a dominance of family firms; a history of organization agency system; and a generally high level of corruption. All these factors make corporate governance a predominantly vital issue in India.

2. Central issues in Corporate Governance

The fundamental authority structure of the joint-stock company outline of business, in standard, is as follows. The copious shareholders who make a payment to the capital of the business are the definite owners of business. They opt for a Board of Directors to supervise the operations of the company on their behalf. The Board, in turn, hire a quality team of management who actually look after the day-to-day functioning of the business and account from time to time to the Board. Hence mangers are the scouts of shareholders and work with the objective of optimizing the shareholders' wealth.

Yet, if this authority pattern apprehended in reality, it shall become much more a challenge for the Board to successfully monitor administration. The essential issue is the kind of the indenture between shareholder council and managers impressing the latter on the divulgence of the funds contributed by the former. The main confront comes from the detail that such contracts are necessarily "partial". It is not likely for the Board to entirely instruct administration on the preferred course of accomplishment under every possible business situation. Shleifer and Vishny (1997)

The record of possible situations is substantially extended. As a result, no contract can be encouraged between representatives of shareholders and the management that detail the right line of action in every circumstances, so that the administration can be held for infringement of such a contract in the occasion it does amazing else under the circumstances. Because of this "partial contracts" situation, some "outstanding powers" over the finances of the company must be regulated with the support of either the financiers or the management. Undoubtedly the earlier does not have the proficiency or the proclivity to sprint the business in the situations unspecified in the contract, so these outstanding powers have to go to management. The ingenious restrictions to these powers embrace much of the spotlight of corporate governance.

The authenticity is even further complicated and prejudiced in favor of management. In actual life, managers manipulate an enormous sum of power in joint-stock companies and the normal shareholder has merely anything say in the way his or her funds is used in the company. In companies with extremely dispersed ownership, the manager (the CEO in the American business environment, the Managing Director in British-kind business environment) working with trifling accountability. Most shareholders are not caring about attending the General Meetings to choose or change the Board of Directors and repeatedly grant their "proxies" to the board. Even those that be present at the meeting stumble on it tricky to have a say in the choice of directors as only the management get to propose a line up of directors for voting.

On his part the CEO frequently constitutes the board with his friends and allies who hardly ever differ with him. Time and again the CEO himself is the Chairman of the Board of Directors as well. As a result the decision-making role of the Board is often sternly compromised and the management, who in actuality has the input to the business, can potentially use corporate wherewithal to auxiliaries their own self- interests rather than the wellbeing of the shareholders.

The jeopardize of the Board of Directors in monitoring the actions of management is predominantly marked in the Anglo-Saxon corporate structure everywhere real monitoring is estimated to come from financial markets. The fundamental basis is that shareholders disgruntled with a meticulous management would simply marshal of their shares in the company. As this might drive down the share price, the corporation would become a takeover object. If and when the acquisition in reality takes place, the acquiring company might get rid of the existing management. It is thus the trepidation of a takeover relatively than shareholder action that is theoretical to keep the management candid and on its toes.

This means, however, presume the subsistence of a deep and liquid stock market with extensive informational competence as well as a authorized and economic system contributing to to M&A activity. More frequently than not, these factors do not exist in developing countries like India. An unconventional corporate governance model which is supported by the bank-based economies in countries like Germany where the main bank ("Hausbank" in Germany) provide to the company exercise substantial influence and carries out incessant project-level custody of the management and the decision-making board has legislative body of multiple stakeholders of the firm. Box 1 bestow a brief evaluation of the two systems.

[Box 1 about he re]

Regular areas of management deed that may be sub-optimal or divergent to shareholders' welfare (other than outright stealing) engross excessive administrative compensation; shift pricing, that is carrying out with confidentially owned companies at except- market rates to draw off off funds; decision-making entrenchment (i.e. managers oppose replacement by a superior management) and sub-optimal exercise of liberated cash flows. This after everything else refers to the draw on that managers put the retained paycheck of the company. In the dearth of profitable venture opportunities, these funds are regularly squandered on debatable empire-building reserves and acquisitions while their preeminent exercise is to be paid back to the shareholders.

Keeping a proficient management in streak is only one, although conceivably the most important, of the matter in corporate governance. For all intents and purposes corporate governance deal with effectual protection of the investors' and creditors' rights and these rights can be endangered in quite a few other ways.

For occurrence, family business and corporate groups are familiar in many countries as well as in India. These range from Keiretsus in Japan and Chaebols in Korea to the quite a few family business groups in India like Birlas and Ambanis. Put in the ground- locking and "pyramiding" of corporate power surrounded by these groups make it more intricate for outsiders to follow the business realities of individual companies in these behemoths. In accumulation, administrative control of these businesses are frequently in the hands of a miniature group of people, usually a family, who either own the preponderance stake, or preserve control through the support of extra block holders like financial institutions. Their individual interests, even as soon as they are the majority shareholders, need not match with those of the extra - minority - shareholders. This often lead to expropriation of alternative shareholder value from end to end actions like "tunneling" of corporate gains or resources to other corporate entity within the group. Such violation of minority shareholders' privileges also comprises an significant issue for corporate governance.

One way to resolve the corporate governance trouble is to align the benefit of the managers with so as the shareholders. The fresh rise in stock and option related recompense for top managers in company in the order of the world is a indication of this attempt. A more customary demonstration of this initiative is the truth that family business empires are more often than not headed by a family member. Executive ownership of corporate equity, on the other hand, it has interesting implication for firm value. As management ownership (as a percentage of total shares) keep on rising, firm value is seen to raise for a while (turn over ownership reaches about 5% for Fortune 500 companies), after that falling for a while (when the ownership is in the 5%-25% range, again for Fortune 500 companies) till it begin to increase again. Morck et al (1988). The underlying principle for the turn down in the transitional range is that in with the purpose of range, managers possess adequate to make sure that they keep their jobs get nearer what may and be able to also find ways to construct more wealth all the way through uses of corporate funds to sub-optimal for shareholders.

3. Legal environment, ownership patterns and Corporate Governance

The lawful system of a nation plays a decisive role in creating an successful corporate governance procedure in a country and shielding the rights of investors and creditors. The permissible environments encompass two chief aspects - the fortification offered in the laws (de jure protection) and to what degree the laws are obligatory in real life (de facto protection). Both these aspects take part important roles in shaping the nature of corporate governance in the nation in question.

Recent study has vehemently connected the genesis of the legal system of a nation to the very formation of its financial and economic planning arguing that the association works through the guard given to external financiers of companies -creditors and shareholders. La Porta et al (1997-2002)

Legal system in large amount countries has their ancestry in one of the four distinct legal systems - the English common law, French civil law, German civil

8

law and Scandinavian civil law. The Indian legal system is perceptibly built on the English common law system. Researchers have old two indices for all these countries - a shareholder rights index ranging from 0 (lowest) to 6 (highest) and a rule of law index ranging 0 (lowest) to 10 (highest) - to evaluate the efficient protection of shareholder rights provided in the diverse countries studied. The first index confines the extent to which the written law protected shareholders whilst the latter mirror to what extent the law is enforced in reality.

The English common law countries lead the four systems in the shareholder rights index with an average of 4 (out of a maximum possible 6) followed by Scandinavian-origin countries by an average score of 3 with the French-origin and German-origin countries coming last by average scores of 2.33 each. Thus, English-origin legal systems provide the best protection to shareholder rights. India, for case has a shareholder rights index of 5, maximum in the sample examined - equal to that of the USA, UK, Canada, Hong Kong, Pakistan and South Africa (all English-origin- law countries) and improved than all the other 42 countries in the study including countries like France, Germany, Japan and Switzerland.

The Rule of law index is another story. Here the Scandinavian-origin countries have an average score of 10 - the highest possible - followed by the German-origin countries (8.68), English-origin countries (6.46) and French-origin countries (6.05). Most multifaceted countries have very high scores on this manifestation while developing countries in general have low scores. India, for instance has a score of 4.17 on this index - ranking 41st out of 49 countries deliberated - ahead only of Nigeria, Sri Lanka, Pakistan, Zimbabwe, Colombia, Indonesia, Peru and Philippines. Hence it appear that Indian laws provide great guard of shareholders' rights on document while the function and enforcement of those laws are appalling.

This difference in fortification of shareholders' rights has led to entirely different trajectory of financial and economic developments in the different nations. The English-origin systems spawn the highest number of firms per capita (on average 35.45 companies per million citizens as compared to 27.26 for Scandinavian-origin countries and 16.79 and 10.00 for German and French-origin countries respectively). They are as well the best performers in organizing external finance. The ratio of the stock market capitalization held by minority shareholders (i.e. shareholders other than the three largest shareholders in each company) to the GNP of a country averages a remarkable 0.60 for the English-origin countries, substantially higher than the average ratio for German, Scandinavian and French-origin countries of 0.46, 0.30 and 0.21 respectively. India has 7.79 companies per million citizens, one of the lowest for English-origin countries but higher than many French-origin countries and Germany. As for the relative amount of external capital to GNP, India has a score of 0.31 which put it in the higher half of the sample.

The prime difference between the legal systems in highly developed countries and those in developing countries deceit in enforcement to a certain extent than in the nature of laws- in-books. Enforcement of laws take part a much more imperative role than the quality of the laws in books in influential events like CEO turnover and developing sanctuary markets by purging insider trading. Berglof and Claessens (2004). In an milieu marked by feeble enforcement of property rights and contracts, entrepreneurs and managers find it tricky to signal their obligation to the impending investors, leading to limited external finance and ownership absorption. This principally hurts the progress of new firms and the small and medium enterprises (SMEs). In such a condition many of the typical methods of corporate governance - market for corporate controls, board activity, stand-in fights and executive compensation - lose their tendency. Large block-holding come into sight as the most important corporate governance device with some probable roles for bank monitoring, shareholder activism, employee monitoring and social control.

Apart from the collective features of corporate governance, Asian economies as a group share firm general features that involve the nature of corporate governance in the region. In spite of their considerable variation in financially viable conditions and politico- legal background, most Asian countries are noticeable with concentrated stock ownership and a prevalence of family-controlled businesses while state-controlled enterprise forms an significant segment of the corporate sector in a lot of of these nations. Corporate governance issue has been of decisive importance in Asian countries above all since the Asian crisis which is supposed to have been partially caused by lack of precision and meager corporate governance in East Asian countries. Claessens and Fan (2003)

Research has established the facts of pyramiding and family control of business in Asian countries, chiefly East Asia, though this trait is widespread in India as well. Even in 2002, the typical shareholding of promoters in all Indian

companies were as high as 48.1%. Topalova (2004). It is held that this is a consequence of the ineffectiveness of the officially permitted system in shielding property rights. Concentrated ownership and family be in command of, are important in countries where permissible protection of property rights is comparatively weak. Weak property rights are as well behind the pervasiveness of family-owned businesses -managerial forms that diminish operation costs and asymmetric in turn problems. Poor expansion of external monetary markets also contributes to this ownership model. The outcome of this concentrated ownership by management in Asian countries is not undemanding. Similar to the sound effects for US companies, in several East Asian countries, firm worth rises with main owner's stake but decline as the surfeit of the principal owner's management run over his equity stake raises. Claessens et al (2002).

In Taiwan, family-run companies with minor control by the family perform healthier than those by means of higher control. Yeh et al (2001)

Topical research has also examined the nature and scope of "tunneling" of

funds inside business groups in India. Bertrand et al (2002)

In the 90's Indian business groups obviously tunneled substantial amount of funds up the ownership pyramid in that way niggardly the minority shareholders of companies at lower level of the pyramid of their equitable gains.

Empirical analyses of the possessions of ownership by other (non- family) groups in Asia are comparatively scarce. The state is an vital party in some countries in Asia, especially India and China. The corporate governance means and efficiency in state-controlled companies are usually deemed to mediocre. Several studies demonstrate that accounting routine is lower for state-owned enterprises in China. The non- linear effect of entrenchment are also there with state ownership. Tian (2001).

Institutional investors accomplish an essential guarantee role in up-and-coming markets, but at hand is little confirmation of their efficiency in corporate governance in Asia. Equity ownership by institutional investors akin to mutual funds has incomplete force of performance in India. Sarkar and Sarkar (2000). Ownership by other group like director, foreigners and lending institutions, on the other hand, show to get better performance. In post-liberalization India, distant ownership helps show only if the foreigners constitute the preponderance shareholders. Chhibber and Majumdar (1999).

Antagonistic takeovers are all but missing in Asian countries. The premium for control is

important in most Asian countries and as high as 10% of the share price in Korea (Bae et al (2002). Outside and minority sign in boards as well as contribution by professionals are rare though rising in Asian companies. On the other hand, corporate governance is not fully futile in Asia. In many Asian countries, including India, CEOs are further likely to lose their jobs when corporate performance is poorer. Gibson (forthcoming) and Das and Ghosh (2004). See Box 2 for a discussion of a few archetypal features of Asian companies and their implication for corporate governance.

[Box 2 about here]

In India, enforcement of business laws relics the soft underbelly of the official and corporate governance system. The World Bank's Reports on the observation of Standards and Codes (ROSC) publishes a country-by-country examination of the observance of OECD's corporate governance codes. In its 2004 report on India World Bank (2004), the ROSC found that while India experiential or largely observed most of the principles, it shall do healthier in certain areas. The input of nominee directors from economic institutions to monitoring and supervising board is one such area. Improvements are as well necessary in the enforcement of definite laws and regulations like those related to stock is roll in major exchanges and insider trade as sound as in dealing with infringement of the Companies Act - the moral fiber of corporate governance system in India. Some of the tribulations arise since disconcerted questions about authority issues and powers of the SEBI. As an great example, there have been cases of out-and-out pilfering of investors' funds with companies desertion overnight. The combined efforts of the Department of Company Affairs and SEBI to pin down the offenders have proved to be largely in vain. As for grievances about transmit of shares and non-receipt of dividends whilst the put right rate has been an imposing 95%, there were still over 135,000 complaints in the course of with the SEBI. Thus there is substantial room for step up on the enforcement side of the Indian legal system to help widen the corporate governance means in the country.

4. Corporate Governance in India - a background

The account of the growth of Indian corporate laws is marked by exciting disparities. At sovereignty, India innate one of the world's poorest economies except one which had a industrial unit sector accounting for a tenth of the nationalized product; four functioning stock markets (predating the Tokyo Stock Exchange) with evidently defined rules overriding listing, trading and settlements; a intense equity ethnicity if only among the urban rich; and a banking system sated with well-developed lending customs and resurgence measures. Goswami (2002). In terms of corporate laws and financial system, thus, India emerged far improved and capable when compared to most extra colonies. The 1956 Companies Act as able-bodied as other laws governing the performance of joint-stock companies and defensive the investors' rights built on this foundation.

The commencement of corporate developments in India were noticeable by the managing bureau system that contributed to the birth of discrete equity ownership but also gave mount to the put into practice of organization enjoying control rights excessively superior than their stock ownership. The turn towards collectivism in the decades after sovereignty marked by the 1951 Industries (Development and Regulation) Act as well as the 1956 Industrial Policy Resolution position in place a command and background of licensing, protection and widespread red-tape that bred sleaze and stilted the increase of the corporate sector. The state of affairs grows from bad to of inferior quality in the next decades and dishonesty, favoritism and incompetence became the trademark of the Indian corporate sector. Excessive tax rates confident creative accounting practices and intricate salve structures to beat the system.

In the nonexistence of a developed stock market, the three all-India expansion finance institutions (DFIs) - the Industrial Finance Corporation of India, the Industrial Development Bank of India and the Industrial Credit and Investment Corporation of India - mutually with the condition financial corporations became the main providers of long-term recognition to companies. Along with the government owned common fund, the Unit Trust of India, they also detained large block of shares in the companies they lend to and perpetually had representations in their boards. In this admiration, the corporate governance system resembles the bank-based German model anywhere these institutions might have played a big task in custody their clients on the right track. Regrettably, they were themselves evaluated on the amount quite than quality of their lending and therefore had little inducement for either proper credit assessment or effectual follow- up and monitoring. Their entrant directors routinely serve as rubber-stamps of the running of the day.

With their support, promoters of business in India might really enjoy managerial control with extremely little equity speculation of their own. Borrowers therefore regularly recoup their investment in a little period and then had little inducement to either pay back the loans or run the company. Recurrently they bleed the company with impunity, siphon off funds with the DFI contender directors mute addressees in their boards.

This squalid but ever more recognizable process usually sustained till the company's net value was totally battered. This stage would approach after the corporation has defaulted on its advance obligations for a whilst, but this would be the phase where India's insolvency reform system driven by the 1985 Sick Industrial Companies Act (SICA) might consider it "sick" and refer it to the Board for Industrial and Financial Reconstruction (BIFR).

As soon as a company is registered with the BIFR it wins instant defense from the creditors' claim for at least four years. Between 1987 and 1992 BIFR take well over two years on a standard to reach a choice, after which interlude the delay has about doubled. Very few companies boast emerge successfully from the BIFR and even for companies that required to be liquidated, the legal procedures takes over 10 years on average, by which time the possessions of the company are just about worthless. Protection of creditors' rights has as a result existed only on paper in India. Given this state of affairs, it is hardly astonishing that banks, flush with depositors' funds normally come to a decision to lend only to blue chip companies and commons their funds in government securities.

Financial revelation norms in India have conservatively been superior to most Asian countries though fell short of those in the USA and other higher countries. Rebelliousness with disclosure norms and even the play up of auditor's reports to

Be conventional to the law pull towards you supposed fines with barely any disciplinary action. The Institute of Chartered Accountants in India has not been recognized to take action against erring auditors.

Whereas the Companies Act provides clear directives for maintaining and updating share registers, in realism minority shareholders contain often suffer from irregularities in share transfers and registrations - purposeful or unintentional. Sometimes non-voting privileged shares have been used by promoters to channel funds and divest minority shareholders of their dues. Minority shareholders have from time to time been defrauded by the management enterprise concealed side deals with the acquirers in the comparatively scarce event of corporate takeovers and mergers.

Boards of directors have been in principal ineffective in India in monitoring the actions of management. They are regularly packed with associates and acquaintances of the promoters and managers, in blatant desecration of the spirit of corporate law. The nominee directors from the DFIs, who might and be supposed to have played a above all important role, have typically been bungling or averse to step up to the act. Consequently, the boards of directors contain mainly function as rubber stamps of the management.

For the majority of the post-Independence era the Indian equity markets were not liquid or difficult as much as necessary to put forth useful control over the companies. Listing necessities of exchanges imposed some lucidity, but non-compliance was neither rare nor acted upon. All in all consequently, minority shareholders and creditors in India remained efficiently unprotected in spite of a overabundance of laws in the books.

5. Changes since liberalization

The existence since liberalization has witnessed wide-ranging change in both laws and policy driving corporate governance as well as all-purpose awareness about it. Perchance the solitary, most important development in the field of corporate governance and investor protection in India has been the enterprise of the Securities and Exchange Board of India (SEBI) in 1992 and its steady empowerment since then. Conventional primarily to control and monitor stock trading, it has played a vital role in establishing the essential least ground rules of corporate performance in the country. Concerns about corporate governance in India were, however, largely triggered by a spate of crises in the early 90's - the Harshad Mehta stock market scam of 1992 followed by incidents of companies allotting special shares to their promoter at intensely discounted prices as well as those of companies just becoming extinct with investors' money. Goswami (2002)